You are currently browsing the tag archive for the ‘van der Corput inequality’ tag.
Given two unit vectors in a real inner product space, one can define the correlation between these vectors to be their inner product
, or in more geometric terms, the cosine of the angle
subtended by
and
. By the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, this is a quantity between
and
, with the extreme positive correlation
occurring when
are identical, the extreme negative correlation
occurring when
are diametrically opposite, and the zero correlation
occurring when
are orthogonal. This notion is closely related to the notion of correlation between two non-constant square-integrable real-valued random variables
, which is the same as the correlation between two unit vectors
lying in the Hilbert space
of square-integrable random variables, with
being the normalisation of
defined by subtracting off the mean
and then dividing by the standard deviation of
, and similarly for
and
.
One can also define correlation for complex (Hermitian) inner product spaces by taking the real part of the complex inner product to recover a real inner product.
While reading the (highly recommended) recent popular maths book “How not to be wrong“, by my friend and co-author Jordan Ellenberg, I came across the (important) point that correlation is not necessarily transitive: if correlates with
, and
correlates with
, then this does not imply that
correlates with
. A simple geometric example is provided by the three unit vectors
in the Euclidean plane :
and
have a positive correlation of
, as does
and
, but
and
are not correlated with each other. Or: for a typical undergraduate course, it is generally true that good exam scores are correlated with a deep understanding of the course material, and memorising from flash cards are correlated with good exam scores, but this does not imply that memorising flash cards is correlated with deep understanding of the course material.
However, there are at least two situations in which some partial version of transitivity of correlation can be recovered. The first is in the “99%” regime in which the correlations are very close to : if
are unit vectors such that
is very highly correlated with
, and
is very highly correlated with
, then this does imply that
is very highly correlated with
. Indeed, from the identity
(and similarly for and
) and the triangle inequality
Thus, for instance, if and
, then
. This is of course closely related to (though slightly weaker than) the triangle inequality for angles:
Remark 1 (Thanks to Andrew Granville for conversations leading to this observation.) The inequality (1) also holds for sub-unit vectors, i.e. vectors
with
. This comes by extending
in directions orthogonal to all three original vectors and to each other in order to make them unit vectors, enlarging the ambient Hilbert space
if necessary. More concretely, one can apply (1) to the unit vectors
in
.
But even in the “” regime in which correlations are very weak, there is still a version of transitivity of correlation, known as the van der Corput lemma, which basically asserts that if a unit vector
is correlated with many unit vectors
, then many of the pairs
will then be correlated with each other. Indeed, from the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality
Thus, for instance, if for at least
values of
, then (after removing those indices
for which
)
must be at least
, which implies that
for at least
pairs
. Or as another example: if a random variable
exhibits at least
positive correlation with
other random variables
, then if
, at least two distinct
must have positive correlation with each other (although this argument does not tell you which pair
are so correlated). Thus one can view this inequality as a sort of `pigeonhole principle” for correlation.
A similar argument (multiplying each by an appropriate sign
) shows the related van der Corput inequality
and this inequality is also true for complex inner product spaces. (Also, the do not need to be unit vectors for this inequality to hold.)
Geometrically, the picture is this: if positively correlates with all of the
, then the
are all squashed into a somewhat narrow cone centred at
. The cone is still wide enough to allow a few pairs
to be orthogonal (or even negatively correlated) with each other, but (when
is large enough) it is not wide enough to allow all of the
to be so widely separated. Remarkably, the bound here does not depend on the dimension of the ambient inner product space; while increasing the number of dimensions should in principle add more “room” to the cone, this effect is counteracted by the fact that in high dimensions, almost all pairs of vectors are close to orthogonal, and the exceptional pairs that are even weakly correlated to each other become exponentially rare. (See this previous blog post for some related discussion; in particular, Lemma 2 from that post is closely related to the van der Corput inequality presented here.)
A particularly common special case of the van der Corput inequality arises when is a unit vector fixed by some unitary operator
, and the
are shifts
of a single unit vector
. In this case, the inner products
are all equal, and we arrive at the useful van der Corput inequality
(In fact, one can even remove the absolute values from the right-hand side, by using (2) instead of (4).) Thus, to show that has negligible correlation with
, it suffices to show that the shifts of
have negligible correlation with each other.
Here is a basic application of the van der Corput inequality:
Proposition 2 (Weyl equidistribution estimate) Let
be a polynomial with at least one non-constant coefficient irrational. Then one has
where
.
Note that this assertion implies the more general assertion
for any non-zero integer (simply by replacing
by
), which by the Weyl equidistribution criterion is equivalent to the sequence
being asymptotically equidistributed in
.
Proof: We induct on the degree of the polynomial
, which must be at least one. If
is equal to one, the claim is easily established from the geometric series formula, so suppose that
and that the claim has already been proven for
. If the top coefficient
of
is rational, say
, then by partitioning the natural numbers into residue classes modulo
, we see that the claim follows from the induction hypothesis; so we may assume that the top coefficient
is irrational.
In order to use the van der Corput inequality as stated above (i.e. in the formalism of inner product spaces) we will need a non-principal ultrafilter (see e.g this previous blog post for basic theory of ultrafilters); we leave it as an exercise to the reader to figure out how to present the argument below without the use of ultrafilters (or similar devices, such as Banach limits). The ultrafilter
defines an inner product
on bounded complex sequences
by setting
Strictly speaking, this inner product is only positive semi-definite rather than positive definite, but one can quotient out by the null vectors to obtain a positive-definite inner product. To establish the claim, it will suffice to show that
for every non-principal ultrafilter .
Note that the space of bounded sequences (modulo null vectors) admits a shift , defined by
This shift becomes unitary once we quotient out by null vectors, and the constant sequence is clearly a unit vector that is invariant with respect to the shift. So by the van der Corput inequality, we have
for any . But we may rewrite
. Then observe that if
,
is a polynomial of degree
whose
coefficient is irrational, so by induction hypothesis we have
for
. For
we of course have
, and so
for any . Letting
, we obtain the claim.
(Linear) Fourier analysis can be viewed as a tool to study an arbitrary function on (say) the integers
, by looking at how such a function correlates with linear phases such as
, where
is the fundamental character, and
is a frequency. These correlations control a number of expressions relating to
, such as the expected behaviour of
on arithmetic progressions
of length three.
In this course we will be studying higher-order correlations, such as the correlation of with quadratic phases such as
, as these will control the expected behaviour of
on more complex patterns, such as arithmetic progressions
of length four. In order to do this, we must first understand the behaviour of exponential sums such as
Such sums are closely related to the distribution of expressions such as in the unit circle
, as
varies from
to
. More generally, one is interested in the distribution of polynomials
of one or more variables taking values in a torus
; for instance, one might be interested in the distribution of the quadruplet
as
both vary from
to
. Roughly speaking, once we understand these types of distributions, then the general machinery of quadratic Fourier analysis will then allow us to understand the distribution of the quadruplet
for more general classes of functions
; this can lead for instance to an understanding of the distribution of arithmetic progressions of length
in the primes, if
is somehow related to the primes.
More generally, to find arithmetic progressions such as in a set
, it would suffice to understand the equidistribution of the quadruplet
in
as
and
vary. This is the starting point for the fundamental connection between combinatorics (and more specifically, the task of finding patterns inside sets) and dynamics (and more specifically, the theory of equidistribution and recurrence in measure-preserving dynamical systems, which is a subfield of ergodic theory). This connection was explored in one of my previous classes; it will also be important in this course (particularly as a source of motivation), but the primary focus will be on finitary, and Fourier-based, methods.
The theory of equidistribution of polynomial orbits was developed in the linear case by Dirichlet and Kronecker, and in the polynomial case by Weyl. There are two regimes of interest; the (qualitative) asymptotic regime in which the scale parameter is sent to infinity, and the (quantitative) single-scale regime in which
is kept fixed (but large). Traditionally, it is the asymptotic regime which is studied, which connects the subject to other asymptotic fields of mathematics, such as dynamical systems and ergodic theory. However, for many applications (such as the study of the primes), it is the single-scale regime which is of greater importance. The two regimes are not directly equivalent, but are closely related: the single-scale theory can be usually used to derive analogous results in the asymptotic regime, and conversely the arguments in the asymptotic regime can serve as a simplified model to show the way to proceed in the single-scale regime. The analogy between the two can be made tighter by introducing the (qualitative) ultralimit regime, which is formally equivalent to the single-scale regime (except for the fact that explicitly quantitative bounds are abandoned in the ultralimit), but resembles the asymptotic regime quite closely.
We will view the equidistribution theory of polynomial orbits as a special case of Ratner’s theorem, which we will study in more generality later in this course.
For the finitary portion of the course, we will be using asymptotic notation: ,
, or
denotes the bound
for some absolute constant
, and if we need
to depend on additional parameters then we will indicate this by subscripts, e.g.
means that
for some
depending only on
. In the ultralimit theory we will use an analogue of asymptotic notation, which we will review later in these notes.
Recent Comments